Dynamic Tarriffs: A Peachy Proposition
Tariffs are common political fodder. Candidate Donald Trump called for
punitive tariffs on goods from China and Mexico.[1]
Both Trump and Candidate Hillary Clinton attacked the Trans-Pacific
Partnership,[2] a
free trade agreement negotiated during President Barack Obama’s presidency
that, if ratified, would have united 12 Pacific Rim countries, accounting for
40% of world trade, under common trade rules and (almost) no tariffs.[3]
Tariffs are also the
core of trade negotiations. For decades, trade negotiators pursued the policy
of tariffication, whereby non-tariff trade barriers were converted to tariffs.
Changing qualitative national policies into quantitative import taxes allowed
negotiators to barter ‘apples for apples’ in trade negotiations. While it is
doubtful that decades of work towards tariffication actually reduced the
prevalence of non-tariff barriers,[4]
there has been a consistent and successful effort to reduce tariffs.[5]
Remaining tariffs
often protect sectors with special economic or social importance. It should be
no surprise that agricultural products are some of the most contentious and
difficult areas in which to generate international cooperation. The United
States maintains punitive tariffs on sugar.[6]
Mexico has similar import taxes on poultry.[7]
Canada protects dairy production with high tariffs on butter, cheese, and other
dairy products.[8]
Negotiators have struggled for most of the 21st century to reach
meaningful agreements on agricultural barriers to trade.[9]
Tariff schedules are
somewhat static documents. Negotiators sit down at the table representing one tariff
schedule and leave the table clutching another tariff schedule. Once the new
tariff schedule is ratified by a negotiator’s government, those tariffs remain
in place until the countries reconvene to negotiate new tariff schedules. A
tariff schedule generally represents a country’s bound tariff commitments, the
highest rates that the country will apply to any particular import. Therefore,
countries retain the right, through unilateral action, to reduce tariffs.
Now to the peaches.
The 2017 peach harvest in the United States is far short of pre-season
expectations. South Carolina and Georgia, America’s second and third largest producers
after California, are set to grow just 10-25% of last year’s crop.[10]
California, responsible for about 75% of America’s total peach yield in 2015, is
also having a down year.[11]
According to the California Cling Peach Board (CCPB), 2017 peach tonnage
to-date is 40% of last year’s total.[12]
The CCPB’s data is incomplete for two reasons: it only reports data from three
processors and also only represents peaches destined for canning. Despite these
shortcomings, the data is probably indicative of a larger shortfall in
California yield. The supply squeeze is evident in pricing. Farm prices for
peaches have increased over 40% between July 2016 and July 2017.[13]
Consumers have been spared the pain of higher prices because grocers have
internalized lower margins, decreasing from about 200% in 2016 to 100% in 2017.[14]
The domestic peach
market is distorted by tariffs during harvest season. Any peaches imported
between June 1 and November 30 are subject to a tariff of either $0.002 or
$0.011 per kilogram depending on its origin.[15]
These tariffs disappear during the rest of the year, opening up the U.S. market
to imports during domestic producers’ off-season. Some countries are exempt
from the peach tariffs because they benefit from U.S. free trade agreements or unilateral
trade preference programs. However, none of the major peach producing
countries: China, Italy, and Spain, have zero-tariff access to America’s peach
market during harvest season.[16]
Maintaining tariffs
when domestic production is suffering from natural causes is bad policy.
Tariffs in this environment do not protect growers in any meaningful way. Georgian
and South Carolinian growers, whose crops have been devastated by natural
causes, must rely on insurance payments, rather than market sales, to get
through the year. Tariffs do them no good. Meanwhile, any tariff-free imports
of fresh peaches would probably only serve to fill out the supply base to
satisfy demand at retail, rather than displacing California growers. It is
quite likely that California peach growers are cost competitive at the farm
level and are cost advantaged compared to imports after transportation is
factored in. Therefore, without the peach tariff in place this year, Californian
producers would make a little less per peach relative to what they are making
in the market today, but their rents to not justify maintaining the tariff.
Without the tariff in place this year, California growers would receive a price
similar to what they expected if Georgia and South Carolina were producing at
full capacity, meaning that they would not lose any revenue relative to their
pre-season expectations. Meanwhile, grocers and consumers would be protected
from domestic supply disruptions because of the increased availability of
imports. In sum, eliminating the peach tariff this year would only impose a
small actual marginal revenue loss on California growers, and no revenue loss
against pre-season expectations, and would have no impact on Georgia and South
Carolina growers. On the other hand, maintaining the peach tariff this year hurts
downstream customers by increasing the price of direct supply substitutes. In
the case of the 2017 peach harvest, grocers’ profitability suffers, and the
financial pinch could just as easily have been passed directly on to end
consumers.
Despite the access
to nearly real-time market data, freedom to lower tariffs at-will, and a strong
policy case to do so, there is surprising little dynamism to the application of
tariffs. The most common mechanism through which tariffs are temporarily
eliminated is when Congress passes Miscellaneous Tariff Bills.[17]
These bills usually suspend tariffs on various products for a renewable period
of two or three years. There is no mechanism for Congress, the President, or the
United States Trade Representative to react in real time to non-trade related
market disruptions.
This inflexibility
can be remedied. Congress can delegate responsibility for tariff deviations to
the USTR or Commerce Department, identifying specific situations, such as when
natural causes decimate commodity crops, when the agency may lower tariffs,
thereby saving American consumers from higher prices without reducing producers’
pre-season expectations. There are already established administrative processes,
such as those used in the context to anti-dumping investigations, which are
designed to apply real-time market data to tariff rates. Generally, these
processes are used to revise tariffs upwards and protect domestic production
interests. However, these same processes can be adapted to drive consideration
of market data in pursuit of lower tariffs. The biggest barrier to implementing
such an adapted process is a classic public choice problem: producers monitor
their economics closely and organize to protect their interests, while
consumers do not track the impact of particular tariffs on their cost-of-living
nor do they organize to fight them. At least in the case of peaches, we have a
good example through which to build awareness about the costs of an inefficient
system.
[1] https://www.marketplace.org/2016/01/15/world/reality-behind-trumps-call-tariffs
[2] http://www.politifact.com/truth-o-meter/article/2016/jul/22/comparing-economic-agendas-hillary-clinton-and-don/
[3] http://www.bbc.com/news/business-32498715.
No tariffs is not entirely true. For example, the United States’ tariff
schedule included import taxes on various chocolate products that were only to
be completely phased out, in some cases, over twenty years after the TPP went
into force. See Tariff Schedule of the United States, available at https://ustr.gov/trade-agreements/free-trade-agreements/trans-pacific-partnership/tpp-full-text.
[4] https://s3.amazonaws.com/academia.edu.documents/39687165/A_Preliminary_Analysis_on_Newly_Collecte20151104-10363-g03i9y.pdf?AWSAccessKeyId=AKIAIWOWYYGZ2Y53UL3A&Expires=1502819112&Signature=Wfu0vNzX0yoMOokaHOe9MUrQtv0%3D&response-content-disposition=inline%3B%20filename%3DA_PRELIMINARY_ANALYSIS_ON_NEWLY_COLLECTE.pdf
[5] https://www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/whatis_e/tif_e/agrm2_e.htm
[6] http://wtocenter.vn/sites/wtocenter.vn/files/err176.pdf
[7]
Id.
[8]
Id.
[9] https://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/agric_e/negoti_e.htm
[10] https://www.nytimes.com/2017/05/30/dining/peach-crop-georgia-south-carolina.html
[11] https://www.statista.com/statistics/193929/top-10-peach-producing-us-states/
[12] http://calclingpeach.com/crop-statistics/
[13] http://www.producepriceindex.com/
[14]
Id.
[15] https://hts.usitc.gov/?query=peach
[16] http://www.worldatlas.com/articles/world-s-top-peach-producing-countries.html.
See also, https://hts.usitc.gov/?query=peach
[17] https://ustr.gov/issue-areas/industry-manufacturing/industrial-tariffs/miscellaneous-tariff-bills
Comments
Post a Comment