Autonomous Vehicles and the Future of Transportation
This semester I enrolled in Autonomous Vehicles and Local Government.
Our class is divided into 15 groups, each with a different focus, and each
group must develop policy recommendations and legal language for Boston by the
end of the semester. My group focuses on how Boston can use its curbs and
streets to ensure that autonomous vehicles are adopted in a way that furthers
Boston’s stated goals of decreasing climate emissions and making its
transportation system more equitable. Over the course of the semester, the
class engaged with weekly readings, videos, and guest lecturers, culminating in
short responses. My eight responses are compiled below, along with a longer reflection.
1.
What are Autonomous Vehicles?
Autonomous vehicle technology is
under-deployed for narrow uses.
There are still serious engineering
and marketing problems impeding widespread commercialization of autonomous
vehicles. First, sensor costs are still rather high. TheHUB video posited that
fully autonomous systems add about $10,000 to a car. Kelly Blue Book estimates
that the average price of a new car in 2018 is $36,270. Adding an additional
28% in costs onto the average retail price of cars is a hefty upcharge.
Moreover, the average American car is almost 12 years old, which hints at the
unaffordability of new cars for many people at today’s prices. Admittedly,
there are financing models (service fleets) and technological progress (cheaper
and better sensors) that can rectify this issue. Emilio Frazzoli of NuTonomy
does not think sensors are a major adoption barrier. Second, high definition
maps and ground-based systems that augment GPS are not widely distributed. By
way of comparison, a few major American airports are just now experimenting
with complicated and expensive ground-based GPS enhancers that significantly increase
the accuracy of the GPS output. Without this system in place, commercial
airliners must land in inclement weather using ground-based radio signals.
Autonomous vehicles need similar map granularity and/or augmentation systems wherever
they operate; not just down to the space of a single runway. Yet, again, Emilio
Frazzoli thinks that HD maps will become ubiquitous. Third, Sertac Karaman
raised some yet unsolved programming issues, such as how to sequence vehicles
at high-traffic intersections. Other programming issues revolve around the use
of cheaper sensors, like cameras, which solve the price issue raised above, but
are then harder to work with in inclement conditions.
Even with these issues, there are
still a range of operations that autonomous vehicles can undertake. JFK and
SFO, two of America’s busiest airports, currently run autonomous Airtrains.
Similarly, the Honolulu Rail Transit Project is an operational autonomous
train. The functionality of these systems is facilitated by what Chris Gerdes
called the “operational design domain.” As he said, autonomous systems are
easier to deploy when the operational parameters are narrow. Autonomous trains
do not interact with other vehicles, run along predetermined routes, and stop
at specified locations. Autonomous vehicles as popularly conceptualized can
also be deployed today for similar narrow uses, with the benefit that their
technology and design is such that their operational domain can expand as the
software improves, uses are tested elsewhere, society accepts their broader
integration, and infrastructure adapts. For example, the MBTA SL1 and SL2 lines
might be made autonomous. These buses encounter more uncertainties than
autonomous trains, but their routes are still narrowly defined, their lanes are
often separated from other traffic, and they also stop at predetermined
locations. As the capabilities of autonomous buses are proven, they might then
be expanded to other lines. Unfortunately, deployment in even these narrow
cases is impeded by technological path-dependency and/or slow fleet turnover,
workforce resistance, tepid public response, and safety concerns.
2.
What Legal Powers Does Boston Have?
Legal authority to install
infrastructure-to-vehicle (I2V) and V2I communication technology is split
between Massachusetts and Boston. However, layered on top of that authority is
a Federal ‘command-and-control’ framework for spectrum that limits innovation.
In some domains, where power
resides is relatively clear. M.G.L.A. 85 § 2 provides that the Massachusetts
department of highways “shall erect and maintain on state highways … and on all
main highways between cities and towns … mechanical traffic signal systems,
[and] traffic devices ….” Similarly, Boston’s Transportation Department has the
“power to make, erect, and maintain … traffic signs, signals, markings and
other devices for the control of street traffic in the city ….” Therefore, the
State has authority over highways while the City has authority within its
boundaries, excluding the highways.
There are some spaces where legal
authority is not so clear. Specifically, the Massachusetts Bay Transportation
Authority (MBTA) is a cooperative State-City transportation authority.
Deliberations must be in consultation with local officials, since the MBTA
Advisory Board, which represents cities and towns in MBTA’s service area, has certain
veto powers. Still, decisions are often made by Massachusetts officials. Most
members of the MBTA Fiscal and Management Control Board are also members of
Massachusetts Department of Transportation (MassDOT), and MBTA’s General
Manager is also MassDOT’s Rail and Transit Administrator. When the MBTA runs
Bus Rapid Transit (BRT), such as the recent Roslindale pilot, most of the
infrastructure it uses is probably Bostonian. To the extent the bus runs on
City property, it uses City infrastructure over which Boston has authority. But
if BRT requires barrier separation from other traffic within Boston, does that
infrastructure development fall within City jurisdiction or MBTA jurisdiction?
And if it falls under MBTA jurisdiction as far as power to build and maintain,
will MBTA utilize City standards to the extent they differ from State
standards? Also, will MBTA be willing to invest in vehicles with V2X/X2V
capabilities alongside City investment in such infrastructure technology?
City standards may differ from Massachusetts’
uniform traffic sign standards. These standards “conform to” Federal highway
standards and are found in the MassDOT Standard Sign Book. In fact, Federal
regulations require that the Sign Book maintain “substantial conformance” with
Federal standards. 23 C.F.R. § 655.603(b). Yet, despite the Federal conformance
mandate, the Sign Book reads more like a compilation of “sign faces in use
throughout the Commonwealth,” which “may be used,” by cities and towns as
opposed to a mandatory set of rules that aim to achieve statewide uniformity.
More importantly for present
purposes, Federal and State sign standards seem only relate to physical
human-interactive aspects of signage. The standards are specific as to aspects
of sign dimensions, colors, fonts, and reflectivity. This leaves a major gap in
regulation of installation of communications technology. But what, at first,
seems like a gap that might beget opportunity for Boston to creatively install
leading edge technology, is actually heavily regulated by the Federal
government through spectrum allocation.
I have reached the suggested limit
of our blog posts, so I will leave the details of Federal spectrum regulation
to someone else. To sum up, Boston enjoys substantial authority to install
traffic management technology within its boundaries. A couple big challenges,
assuming buy-in to such innovation from City officials, are coordination with
MBTA and navigating the constraints of Federal spectrum allocation.
3.
What Are State and Federal Government Actors Doing?
The American Vision for Safer
Transportation through Advancement of Revolutionary Technologies (AV START) Act
establishes “a committee to make policy recommendations to Congress regarding
HAV data ownership, control, and access,” to improve vehicle safety. The
committee can look to the National Aeronautics and Space Administration’s
(NASA) Aviation Safety Reporting System (ASRS) as an example of a
well-functioning incident reporting mechanism that contributes to improved
transportation safety.
ASRS has two objectives:
1)
Improve the national airspace system (NAS); and
2)
Enhance the database for human factors research and recommendations within the
NAS.
ASRS achieves these objectives
through voluntary, confidential, and non-punitive reporting. Anybody involved
in aircraft operations may voluntarily submit incident reports to NASA about
any unsafe occurrence or hazardous situation. After review by ASRS staffers,
the reports are de-identified by removing the report’s “ID Strip,” which
contains the reporter’s personal information. Once the incident information is
coded into the ASRS Database, both the physical and electronic copies of the
original report is destroyed to ensure confidentiality. Finally, the Federal Aviation
Administration (FAA) will not, in most cases, levy a civil penalty nor suspend
an aviator’s certificate if that person filed a report with ASRS within 10 days
of the incident.
In place since 1976, ASRS has a
long and successful record. In 2017, the program received over 94,000 reports,
over half from air carrier pilots. Those reports helped improve the NAS. Some
recent examples of system improvement include clarifying airport maps,
enhancing airplane manuals, and renaming navigation reference points with
confusing names.
This type of incident reporting
system can be adapted to autonomous vehicles.
A reporting system can be
implemented when drivers and autonomous technologies co-exist. The purposes of
such a system would mirror those of the ASRS: to improve system safety and
enhance human factors research. The fact that most ASRS reports are submitted
by professional pilots suggests that any autonomous vehicle reporting should
also focus on incentivizing professional drivers like long-haul truckers, van
drivers, and taxi drivers. And the safety improvements might mirror those from
the ASRS: updating maps, learning about vehicle component malfunctions, or
redesigning traffic signs.
A reporting system can also be
implemented independently of drivers for completely autonomous vehicles.
Vehicles might periodically push sample data to a federal database or report
any activity outside specific parameters. Again, the objectives and
improvements might mirror the ASRS.
Many programmatic ASRS elements
must be reconceived for autonomous vehicle implementation. Is the Department of
Transportation the best agency to manage an incident database? Will states
provide qualified immunity to vehicle operators, whether they be drivers,
manufacturers, or fleet owners, for most or certain road infractions,
incidents, or accidents if reports are filed? What information should be
collected, how much flexibility should reporters be allowed to provide data,
and in what format should the data be provided? These are just a few of the
questions that the AV START committee will grapple with, and reviewing the ASRS
is a good place for the committee to start.
4.
The TNC Story in Boston and Elsewhere: What Facts Do We Have?
The facts of TNC usage are leading
cities to reallocate curb space. Cities should continue to actively experiment
with curb usage as transportation dynamics change.
Several of the pieces mention
similar TNC usage patterns. TNCs experience high usage outside of peak travel
times, between 8 PM and 6 AM. TNC adoption is higher among younger people,
especially the 25-35 age range. TNC usage increases with disposable income, the
minimum threshold appears to be about $50,000 with even higher usage at higher
incomes.
Several pieces also cite similar
reasons that people use TNCs. The two that specifically interest me are (1) to
avoid drinking and driving and (2) when public transportation is not consistent
or is closed.
These facts are not lost on cities.
Washington D.C. recently decided to redesign some of its curb space near Dupont
Circle. Dupont Circle is a hub of nightlife activity, with official bar and
club capacity for about 17,000 people on any given night. Started back on
August 30, and continuing for the next year, curbs that used to be 60 free
parking spots in the area on Thursday, Friday, and Saturday nights will be
dedicated pick-up and drop-off space for TNCs from 10 PM to 7 AM.
Boston might adopt similar policy
for similar areas. Faneuil Hall is a well-known nightlife hub. The area where
North Street connects Congress and Cross Streets is surrounded by bars and
restaurants. “Walking” along North Street in Google Street View, signs inform
drivers that there is “No stopping 7am–6pm. Except Sat & Sun.” and that the
area is a “Tow Zone. Cab Stand 6pm–7am.” This particular street, then, might be
too lenient for cabs, which can clog up streets during busy times like 6:30 pm
and also too lenient towards non-hire vehicles that might stop at the curb on Saturday
night, blocking out taxis and TNCs. This street and others like it are ripe
candidates for experimentation.
The general idea is simple and
tested – reallocate curbside parking to dedicated and necessary use to reduce
street congestion. Manhattan is a great example of curb allocation in action.
One curb section might change from parking, to empty (for cleaning), to
loading/unloading, before beginning its cycle anew. The policy trick is
deciding what curb use is most valuable.
The two reasons that people cite
for using TNCs can guide policymakers’ focus in looking for areas ripe for curb
reallocation. Areas with a high concentration of bars and restaurants. Areas
with a high concentration of professional services or others who work long or
odd hours. Areas around public transportation itself, even when that
transportation is not running. In tandem with following citizens’ desires,
cities can and should rely on facts when making these allocation decisions.
There is a wealth of data on pick-up and drop-off locations and times. One
example is the
publicly available New York City taxi data. Combined, understanding
peoples’ preferences and usage data are powerful enablers to make streets more
responsive, dynamic, and efficient.
5.
What Levers Does a City Have? What is Singapore Doing?
Several cities are integrating
transportation network companies (TNCs) and autonomous vehicles into their
public transportation networks. Phoenix is working with Waymo to pilot first
mile-last mile service for certain customers. Gothenburg, Sweden launched an
autonomous bus. And Charlotte, North Carolina has partnered with Lyft in an
attempt to make that City’s public transportation more flexible, dynamic, and
responsive. Integrating autonomous vehicles into public transportation networks
provides cities a hook to exercise potentially significant of leverage over
TNCs and autonomous vehicle operators: the request for proposals (RFPs).
RFPs are documents that announce
what the publishing entity wants to buy. Public buyers are subject to various
rules about how to promulgate RFPs and review sellers’ bids to pick winners. Without
getting too hung up on the details, public procurement law in Europe (similar
principles apply in the US, but I am only familiar with Europe’s rules) regulates
process, transparency, and discrimination, but leaves substance largely to the
public agency.
Public RFPs are also big business.
According to the OECD, public spending in the United States fluctuated between
25-30% of total gross domestic product for at least the past 10 years. While
the Federal annual budget is close to a whopping $4 trillion, states spend
about $1.3 trillion annually and localities add another $1.5 trillion per year.
Of that, about $300 billion flows into transportation. There is a lot of money
to be made providing services, and transportation services, at governments’
behest.
Substantive procurement discretion
couples with funding to provide governments with leverage that they can use to
learn more about autonomous vehicles, control how autonomous vehicles are
deployed, and more. Governments’ leverage is enhanced by the fact that
autonomous vehicle operators seem aware that they need government cooperation
to realize the potential of this nascent technology, so winning cooperative projects
can separate market winners from pretenders.
The potential power of public
procurement can be seen in Singapore’s 122 page Request for Information.
Singapore asks for more than just data – it asks for a comprehensive plan and
vision, which will help its decision-makers understand how well bidders’ dreams
mesh with their own. Singapore also poses many questions about privacy,
maintenance, and pricing, which will elicit numerous ideas and help Singaporean
authorities to engage creatively with new modes of implementation. Singapore
seems to be using its RFI quite effectively – other cities can do the same.
6.
Labor Issues (in NYC)
This week’s articles paint a rather
bleak picture. Drivers are psychologically manipulated by companies that enjoy
informational and organizational advantages. The legal relationship is hollowed
from a regulated employment contract to a mere use contract. And, in response,
activists beat the old war drums for supply limitations or minimum wages. It is
no wonder that Mr. Ochisor was “mad at the politicians,” and “mad at Silicon
Valley.” The status of TNC drivers presents an opportune example to explore our
assumptions about the legality of employment.
Employment contracts are the
legalized rental of humans. In England you can “hire” a car much like Cravath
might “hire” an HLS graduate. The idea of employment as human rental was openly
pronounced in the canonical economics textbook Economics, by Paul Samuelson.
Modern human rental reflects old
ideology about consent. One line of justification for monarchical rule rested
on the consent of the people. However, that consent did not limit the monarch
to representing his subjects’ will – it was not a delegation from “we the
people” to the monarch – but was a complete alienation of power and
decision-making. This same consent-as-alienation idea also justified voluntary
slave and coverture marriage contracts. We now largely agree that
consent-as-alienation is an unacceptable intellectual and legal structure for
the examples just cited. Yet corporate workers are subject to the same loss of
power in the employment context that the people, slaves, and wives were in those
other contexts.
Corporations are major governance
institutions. They make a range of vitally important decisions from building
factories, to investing in employees’ retirement, to lobbying for or against
technical regulations, and on down the line. And corporations are not
democracies. Some of America’s largest public companies, like Facebook, are
controlled through dual-class voting shares by their founders. Even in other
public companies, and Uber is considering going public at a $120 billion
valuation, decision-making is largely left to executive management, sometimes
with input from billionaire investors. At no point in this story do ‘retail
investors’ or rented humans have any meaningful input.
In the context of Uber, recognizing
that drivers give up their autonomy interests through rental contracts that
alienate their decision-making power to Dara Khosrowshahi makes the legal
battle about classifying them as employees or independent contractors a bit
quaint. Sure, drivers-as-employees have more protections in their legal rental
relationship than they do as contractors. In either case, however, the drivers barely
make enough to survive, much less capture the full value of their work, and are
disenfranchised from influencing decisions about a subject which they know
better than almost anyone else.
The issue is two-fold. The first is
democratic. The democratic deficit in private sector governance is a
problematic flaw in our society. The second is economic. Income inequality is
much smaller than wealth inequality, and ownership, not wages, beget wealth.
Human rental excludes workers from both.
7.
Los Angeles’ Public Transportation Department
This week’s materials, especially
the conversation with Scott Corwin and Seleta Reynolds, induced me to reexamine
the nature of public transportation agencies. In particular, Corwin and
Reynolds disagreed about whether public agencies have the capacity to create a
viable and popular MaaS platform that integrates all modes of transportation
around a metropolitan area. Reynolds thinks it is preferable over
public-private partnerships, while Corwin thinks private developers are
necessary. While Corwin’s position strikes me as more probable, I think cities
and their transportation departments should reimagine their capacity to act as
MaaS providers.
The typical transportation model
inserts public transportation as an alternative system to private
transportation. Sometimes the two are in competition; sometimes they are
complementary. Each runs different modes (trains versus cars) and capacities
(bus versus small car). In many ways, both public and private transportation
fill gaps left by the other system. In the traditional model, both private and
public own and operate transportation assets to meet needs unfulfilled by the
other system.
City agencies could reimagine their
role from that of an asset-heavy transportation system operator to one of an
asset-light transportation coordinator, much like TNCs but on a much broader,
multi-modal scale. What would this entail? First, a city must have robust
internal software development and data privacy teams. A desirable MaaS
application will take an enormous amount of back- and front-end development.
Second, the city could progressively sell its transportation assets to private
operators, perhaps with some contractual covenants that the assets, or better
yet their seating equivalents, will not be retired from the metro
transportation system for at least a certain amount of time. Third, that city
would need to use monetary incentives to induce private actors to service
underserved areas. Those incentives might be allocated through credit given
directly to low-income households. Fourth, the asset-light transportation
department should also use monetary incentives to encourage the use and
development of preferred modes. Just because a city steps away from owning the subway
does not mean that it should not continue to encourage subway ridership.
An asset-light public
transportation model has several redeeming characteristics. It makes public
transportation agencies much more flexible. They might allocate substantial funds
to subsidize subway ridership today and shift those funds to shared autonomous
vehicles later. Relatedly, cities could be more responsive to citizens by
changing transportation budgets as needs arise rather than suffering the
path-dependency induced by asset purchases. Also, cities would have much better
data about when and how their population travels, enabling much smarter
allocation of transportation subsidies to serve the underserved and enhance
efficiencies.
That data is critical to developing
a core asset that I don’t think cities can privatize: transportation
infrastructure. No matter how asset-light cities get they still need to build
roads. The questions that cities need to answer is how and where to build to
support the transportation dynamics of their city. Shifting public investment
from operational asset investment to platform provision and systemic nudging
would provide unprecedented insight and dynamic influence.
8.
Electric Vehicles, Autonomous Vehicles, and Regional Energy Issues
When I worked for Ford Motor
Company I drove a Fusion plug-in hybrid. Unfortunately, I lived in a big old
multi-building, multi-unit complex that did not have EV parking, so the
all-electric range went virtually unused. My story is an example of why initiatives
like Vermont’s EV Readiness Building Codes are important to support the
adoption of EVs.
Vermont’s program requires
multifamily developments with more than 10 units to make at least 4% of parking
spaces EV-ready, as well as establishing requirements for new commercial
buildings. Establishing EV requirements for new buildings is a relatively
efficient regulation. It is cheaper to install wiring and infrastructure during
site construction than to retrofit existing sites. Also, electrifying new
parking will match the roll-out of EV-enabled parking with actual vehicle
adoption.
However, the impact of EV-ready
parking in multifamily housing should not be overstated. People who rent tend
to be younger, poorer, and more urban. Therefore, they are also less likely to
own, lease, or use cars, especially new cars. That said, those who live in
buildings without EV-enabled parking have no choice about whether to join the
growing EV market, and there are surely many who would join the EV market, if
given the infrastructure.
It seems like there are at least
two things states can do to enhance the value of their EV-ready building codes.
First, states can enhance the value
of their EV-ready building codes by digitizing the location and type of
charging available when those chargers are installed. In this way, cities will
have a database ready to support a future of ubiquitous electric fleets (or any
other future in which it may be useful). It is possible that those fleets will
use centralized charging, but they may also need access to some distributed
charging and the pre-installed capacity can serve that need. The UC Davis
policy brief frets that charging installed for personal-use vehicles may not be
well-suited for autonomous fleets. I agree, but we do not know yet whether that
is true or not. By the time autonomous fleets scale, it is quite likely that
charging infrastructure will go through at least one generation of development,
allowing for a rethink and redeployment of charging facilities, if they are
actually very badly deployed for fleet operations. If states digitize the
EV-charging network, they should also require owners to periodically update the
state on the status of those chargers, so uninstalled or inoperable stations do
not remain in the digital network.
Second, they might push for
EV-readiness in new developments and homes, which would help enable richer,
older, and more rural populations. They could require developers to include
fast-chargers in a certain percentage of new homes or at every block. Or they
might engage in information and marketing campaigns to encourage individual
homeowners who are remodeling or rebuilding to install advanced EV charging.
Even if the homeowner does not use the infrastructure, it might increase the
home’s resale value.
9.
Reflective Essay
I enrolled in this class to stay
updated on the development of autonomous vehicles, understand better how they
might change transportation, and think about policy interventions to encourage
the augmentation of their benefits and mitigate their negative consequences.
The lab serves all of those goals and more. Particularly, Group 3’s work on
policy recommendations for Boston’s curbs and streets is interacting
unexpectedly with the views that I am forming around autonomous vehicle
development, and shifting my focus when thinking about the lab. More concretely,
I am skeptical about the timeline for the roll-out of fully autonomous vehicles
with car-equivalent operational freedom. This skepticism feeds directly into
how I approach developing policy recommendations for Boston’s built
environment, targeted towards achieving Boston’s 2030 goals and in the context
of the generational battle to redesign society towards net zero emissions.
Fully autonomous and operationally
unconstrained vehicles hold enormous transformational potential. I love
dreaming about the death of personal car ownership, eradication of unused
parking, a dynamic and efficient transportation network with near-perfect
safety, and distributed batteries that not only power the vehicles but also store
energy from intermittent renewable sources. But these dreams cannot be
implemented today because they do not align with the current state of
autonomous vehicle, much less battery, technology.
The lab’s opening materials on
technological substance were very informative in this regard. John Leonard was
especially impactful. His personal experience with autonomous vehicles of all
kinds gave credibility to his skepticism about the timeline for the development
of the technologies that underlie autonomous road transport. That lecture
dovetailed with Emilio Frazzoli’s lecture demonstrating autonomous vehicle
capabilities from many years ago, as well as NuTonomy representatives
discussing the truly circumscribed, narrow nature of their operational mandate.
This information conformed to my prior experience.
I came to the lab with a notion
that autonomous vehicle commercialization might be slower than advertised. That
said, my perception of the commercialization timeline became compressed the
more time I spent away from autonomous vehicle engineers. In fact, in my first
post I struck an optimistic tone, claiming that autonomous vehicles might be used
today in circumscribed operational environments like bus rapid transit.
However, hearing from engineers has re-implanted my commercialization
incrementalism. For example, a guest speaker (I believe it was a NuTonomy employee)
mentioned the radically different physics of Boston buses compared with small
personal cars, and the difficulty of translating NuTonomy’s experience to such
a different vehicle. Moreover, NuTonomy’s outlook on how the business might
develop is a bit pessimistic, especially for a city like Boston. That is,
autonomous vehicle companies will monopolize particular metro markets because
generalizing to different cities is too hard.
This view of the commercialization
of autonomous vehicle technology as a slower incremental process has a direct
impact on my group work. Put bluntly, when thinking about changes Boston might
make to curbs and streets in the short-term, and even in the medium- or
long-term, in many instances it is better to ignore the possibility for
autonomous vehicle deployment. Several factors are especially relevant to this
conclusion.
First, Boston has particular
transportation goals. There are myriad goals listed in the Go Boston 2030
report. Listing a few suffices to make the point. Boston aims to reduce
regional vehicle miles traveled by 5.5% below 2005 levels by 2020. The city
wants to reduce greenhouse gas emissions from transportation by 50% of 2005
levels by 2030. And Boston wants to reduce the transportation cost burden for
very low income citizens from 33% of income to 13%.
Second, Boston has particular
emissions goals. One was already mentioned: 50% reduction in transportation
emissions below 2005 levels by 2030. Boston’s environmental goals are not the isolated
environmentalist concerns of a liberal coastal city. They interact with
international action, emanating from the Paris Climate Agreement, and the
evolving science and experience about how we need to change our society to both
mitigate further harm and also adapt to a new climate reality. Go Boston 2030
acknowledges that 25% of Boston greenhouse gas emissions are from
transportation sources.
Third, nobody knows exactly how
autonomous vehicle technology will be commercialized. Many companies envision a
world where autonomous Uber fleets roam city streets and serve most
transportation needs. But so far, that is not the world we see. Driver assist
technologies, close cousins of autonomous vehicle technologies, are today
commercialized through the sale of private vehicles. As discussed above,
autonomous vehicles might be commercialized through proof-of-concept
single-type-operations like particular bus routes, subject to regulatory
approval or simply out of an abundance of caution. Even in a ubiquitous fleet
world, private car ownership will not disappear overnight. The average car is
well over 10 years old, and so does not have the embedded technology to be
easily upgraded into an autonomous actor, and it will take some time for cars
to age out of use.
Fourth, nobody knows exactly how
autonomous vehicle commercialization will interact with other types of
technology. Autonomous vehicles as tested by Waymo or Uber may turn out to be
the best way, or even just a socially serviceable way, to store and use
intermittent renewable energy. But perhaps autonomous vehicles and battery
technology are better paired in bicycle or scooter-like packages. Along those
lines, competing modes of transport might become unexpectedly favored over
those we see tested today, such as the rise of powered scooters.
Fifth, Boston must exert control over
the means to achieve its transportation and emissions goals, in the context of
uncertain autonomous vehicle commercialization, to design the type of city that
Boston leaders envision. The timelines to achieve those goals do not
necessarily align with the timeline for autonomous vehicle rollout. When John
Leonard polled the class asking when we think autonomous vehicles will reach
commercialization, I picked the farthest date out, which was well past 2030.
Boston leaders, planners, officials, and citizens do not have that much time to
design and implement the city they want to live in, either politically or
environmentally. Politically, Boston officials must take action tomorrow and in
the next few years to improve reliability, and increase access and safety, with
the technology and options at their disposal today. Environmentally, Boston
officials cannot count on autonomous vehicles to be a panacea that brings
emissions to zero. On both fronts, City officials cannot abdicate their
responsibility to actively design a built environment that encourages zero- and
low-emissions transportation in the reality that exists simply because there is
an uncertain utopian technological revolution on the horizon.
Most importantly in this regard, autonomous
vehicle developers will work within the physical and legal parameters set by
Boston. A NuTonomy representative said that the company is building its
vehicles to operate independently from the urban environment. That is, the company
does not want to rely on city infrastructure to guarantee the operational
reliability of its vehicles. I imagine that all autonomous vehicle developers
hold some semblance of a similar attitude. Imbedded in this desire for
operational independence is an implicit recognition that transportation
infrastructure is in many ways a neutral platform. Roads are generally flat and
paved, which makes them open to new technological modes and, if new technology
becomes sufficiently important, the applicable rules-of-the-road can be changed
fairly easily.
Therefore, Boston should plow ahead
and redesign itself to meet its goals in a way that does not rely on autonomous
vehicles. In most cases, policy interventions are neutral towards autonomous
vehicle adoption. For example, reassigning parking spots as pick-up and
drop-off locations is neutral towards the development of autonomous vehicles. More
controversially, encouraging curbside shared-bike access to increase the
catchment areas for trains and buses is autonomous vehicle neutral. Autonomous
vehicles might be implemented in narrow operational domains like trains before
they ever become ubiquitous, in which case such policy supports autonomous
vehicle adoption. However, autonomous vehicles might commercialize in the same
role as the bikes, serving as the first mile/last mile link, in which case the
policy works at cross-purposes to autonomous vehicle adoption. Critically,
nobody knows when nor how autonomous vehicles will roll out, nor their
environmental and social valences. Meanwhile, Boston has promulgated specific
and clear goals outlining the type of city it wants to become.
Comments
Post a Comment